Hu Bin and Debing Zhang (2006)
Cellular-Automata Based Qualitative Simulation for Nonprofit Group Behavior
Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation
vol. 10, no. 1
<https://www.jasss.org/10/1/1.html>
For information about citing this article, click here
Received: 27-Dec-2005 Accepted: 07-Dec-2006 Published: 31-Jan-2006
Figure 1. The Moore neighborhood template |
Figure 2. The distribution of loyalty values |
Figure 3. Function of member's characteristic |
Figure 4. Function of a managerial policy |
(a) | (b) |
Figure 5. Transition of a member's loyalty value on the lattice |
Table 1: The number of possible transitions in Figure 5 | ||||||
W | - | 0 | + | |||
Figure 5 | (a) | (b) | (a) | (b) | (a) | (b) |
Number of transitions | 3 | 4 | 3 | 2 | 3 | 3 |
Di ( t) = 2 |
Di ( t) = √ 12 + 22 |
(a) | (b) |
Figure 6. Calculating the distance between cells |
Ci (0) = Di (0) | (1) |
Following the initial time stage, the interaction between environmental changes and the characteristics of group members can be expected to change Di(t) or Ci(t) correspondingly.
e(t) = Di(t) - Ci(t) | (2) |
where e(t) is the difference between loyalty gravitation and cost gravitation of member i at time stage t. If e(t) < 0, then W= "-". If e(t) = 0, then W= "0". If e(t) > 0, then W= "+". Therefore, at initial time stage (i.e. t = 0), W= "0". When an environmental change occurs at the initial time stage, the resulting change Di(t) or Ci(t), indicating W ≠ "0" and that, therefore, the black ring will move.
Ci(t+1) = Ci(t) + αi | (3) |
Di(t+1) = Di(t) + βi | (4) |
where α i, β i ∈[-1,1].
Table 2: Calculation of α i and β i | |||
Sub-group | Characteristic of member | Economic policy | Social policy |
Formal sub-group or Informal sub-group | Economic being | α i = -Xi·EF (5) | β i = 0.5·EF (7) |
Social being | α i = 0.5·EF (6) | β i = Xi·EF (8) | |
(a) Formation of Equation 5 |
(b) Formation of Equation 6 |
(c) Formation of Equation 8 |
(d) Formation of Equation 7 |
Figure 7. Causality of management policy, characteristic of member and the gravitations |
(9) |
where n is the number of members in the group. Let E(t) = | D(t)- C(t)|. Here the filter functions as follows: At each time stage t the lowest combinations E(t) are kept. All remaining combinations are disregarded.
Figure 8. Conceptual model of CA based qualitative simulation with inputs and outputs |
First: Isolate an example.
Second: Design a sampling of varying inputs, each a differing combination of member characteristics and a change of policies.
Third: Run a simulation of each to yield a corresponding output.
Fourth: Assess process of input to output according to common managerial sense. If these are consistent, then the proposed method is valid. Otherwise it is not.
Table 3: Experimental designs | ||||||||
Experimental runs (first to last) | 1 | 2 | 3 | 4 | 5 | 6 | 7 | 8 |
Characteristic of formal members | EB | EB | EB | EB | SB | SB | SB | SB |
Characteristic of informal members | EB | EB | SB | SB | EB | EB | SB | SB |
Managerial policy | EP | SP | EP | SP | EP | SP | EP | SP |
Figure 9. Initial behavior state of the group (on the lattice) |
Figure 10. Simulation result with experimental design 1 |
Figure 11. Simulation result with experimental design 2 |
Figure 12. Simulation result with experimental design 3 |
Figure 13. Simulation result with experimental design 4 |
Figure 14. Simulation result with experimental design 5 |
Figure 15. Simulation result under experimental design 6 |
Figure 16. Simulation result under experimental design 7 |
Figure 17. Simulation result under experimental design 8 |
Figure 18. E(t) of experimental design 1 |
Figure 19. E(t) of experimental design 2 |
Figure 20. E(t) of experimental design 3 |
Figure 21. E(t) of experimental design 4 |
Figure 22. E(t) of experimental design 5 |
Figure 23. E(t) of experimental design 6 |
Figure 24. E(t) of experimental design 7 |
Figure 25. E(t) of experimental design 8 |
Table 4: A case of a group | ||
Formal sub-group | Number of members | 30 |
Characteristic of members | Normal economic being, 15 Normal social being, 15 | |
Informal sub-group | Number of members | 20 |
Characteristic of members | Normal economic being, 10 Normal social being, 10 | |
Figure 26. The initial behavior state of the group |
(a) Alternative 1 |
(b) Alternative 2 |
(c) Alternative 3 |
(d) Alternative 4 |
Figure 27. Simulation results at the last time stage |
(a) at time stage t = 1 |
(b) at time stage t = 2 |
(c) at time stage t = 3 |
(d) at time stage t = 4 |
Figure 28. Simulation results for Alternative 2 |
(a) at time stage t = 1 |
(b) at time stage t = 2 |
(c) at time stage t = 3 |
(d) at time stage t = 4 |
(e) at time stage t = 5 |
Figure 29. Simulation results for Alternative 3 |
Figure 30. D(t)of Alternative 2 and 3 with simulation runs |
BERENDS P, Romme G (1999) Simulation as a Research Tool in Management Studies. European Management Journal, 17(6). pp.576-583
BLAU P (1964) Exchange and Power in Social Life. Transaction Publishers, New Brunswick
CONTE R, Paolucci M (2002) Reputation in artificial societies: Social beliefs for social order, Norwell: Kluwer Academic Publishers
DIJKUM C, Detombe D and Kuijk E (1999) Validation of Simulation Models. Amsterdam: SISWO (SISWO Publication 403)
FRANK K A, Yasumoto J Y (1998) Linking action to social structure within a system: Social capital within and between subgroups. American Journal of Sociology, 104(3). pp. 642-686
HAYAKAWA H (2000) Bounded rationality, social and cultural norms, and interdependence via reference groups. Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 43. pp.1-34
HEGSELMANN R and Flache A (1998) Understanding Complex Social Dynamics: A Plea For Cellular-automata Based Modelling. Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, 3(1) https://www.jasss.org/1/3/1.html
JANSSEN M and Jager W (1999) An integrated approach to simulating behavioural processes: A case study of the lock-in of consumption patterns. Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, 2(2) https://www.jasss.org/2/2/2.html
KLÜVER J and Stoica C (2003) Simulations of Group Dynamics with Different Models. Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, 6(4) https://www.jasss.org/6/4/8.html
KUIPERS B (1986) Qualitative Simulation. Artificial Intelligence, 29. pp. 289-338
LEWIN K (1951) Field theory in social science. New York: Harper
MAYER, Davis & Schoorman (1999) An integrative model of organizational trust, Academy of Management Review, 20(3). pp. 709-734
PRIEN R L, Rasheed A, Kotulic A G (1995) Rationality in Strategic Decision Processes, Environmental Dynamism and Firm Performance. Journal of Management, 21(5). pp. 913-929
ROBBINS S, Coulter M, Stuart-Kotze R (1997) Management. Ontario: Prentice Hall Canada
VALLACHER R R, Nowak A (1994) Dynamical Systems in Social Psychology, CA: Academic Press
VALLACHER R R, Nowak A (1997) The Emergence of Dynamical Social Psychology. Psychological Inquiry, 8(2). pp. 73-99
Return to Contents of this issue
© Copyright Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, [2006]