Nicole J. Saam and Andreas Harrer (1999)
Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation vol. 2, no. 1, <https://www.jasss.org/2/1/2.html>
To cite articles published in the Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, please reference the above information and include paragraph numbers if necessary
Received: 25-Nov-98 Accepted: 20-Dec-99 Published: 31-Jan-99
Table 1: Alternative representations of norms inside the agents' architectures (norm-abiding systems) | |||
Norms as | built-in constraints: norms are seen as constraints on the agents' action repertoires (behavioural notion); no truly normative choice | build-in ends (goals): cognitive agents are allowed to choose among competing goals (instead of simply applying procedures and routines) but they treat norms like any other of their goals | built-in obligations: explicit and specific mental object; differs from a constraint since it does not automatically reduce the set of actions available to the agents; and from a goal since it is not immediately transformed into a goal |
reliability | high reliability: the constraints will always be executed | low reliability: goals may be abandoned when they clash with competing, more urgent needs | average reliability: agents may give up normative goals, but this will cost them more than abondoning ordinary goals |
learning | no learning: new constraints are implemented when the system is off-line | average learning: build-in ends should be added when the system is off-line; | normative goals are autonomously produced on the grounds of normative beliefs, and in principle beliefs may be acquired when the system is on-line |
novelty | no novelty: constraints reduce available actions; only proscriptions, that is, prohibitions ('Don't ...'), can be represented, but not prescriptions ('Do...') | build-in ends may correspond to prescriptions and not only to prohibitions; but since learning is not granted, there ought to be a one-to-one correspondence between social norms and internal goals with a consequent high computational complexity | normative beliefs may be formulated as prescriptions, and not as mere prohibitions |
repair | no repair: agents are not endowed with the capacity for modifying unsuccessful constraints | goal-oriented systems ought to be able to try out several solutions and choose those that achieve their goals to the highest degree, before giving up their goals | as with any other kind of goal, plans for normative goals are subject to change and repair |
social control | no need | no social control: agents may have preferences corresponding to norms or not; they may cling to these or abandon them as a function of circumstances | since normative goals are a special type of goals, and normative actions have specific costs, agents can be shown to be interested in some monitoring of norms |
actions prescribed are in the interests of a subset of the MAS at the expense of the rest; these are either the norms aimed to restore equity, protecting the interests of underprevileged categories, or, conversely, norms which favour inequality, protecting the interests of the privileged party (e.g. norms defending private property); (Conte and Castelfranchi 1995b: 115f).The concept of partial tutoriality seems to be derived from Ullman-Margalit's 'norms of partiality'. It is complemented by distributive tutoriality (actions prescribed are in the interests of all members of the system) and collective tutoriality (actions prescribed are in the interest of the MAS as a collective, but independent of and outside the interest of its members). Do norms have a function in relation to (in)equality? Remember Ullman-Margalit's third argument: Norms are solutions to problems of inequality.
Table 2: Types of actions in the Conte and Castelfranchi model | ||
Action type | Order of preference among these actions | Cost of action (in food items) |
EAT | 1 | 0 |
MOVE-TO-FOOD-SEEN | 2 | 1 |
MOVE-TO-FOOD-SMELLED | 3 | 1 |
ATTACK | 4 | 4 |
MOVE-RANDOM | 5 | 1 |
STAY | 6 | 0 |
Table 3: The results of the Castelfranci and Conte model | ||||||
Strategy | Str | st.dev. | St.Dev | st.dev. | Agg | st.dev |
Blind Aggression | 4287 | 204 | 1443 | 58 | 9235 | 661 |
Strategic | 4727 | 135 | 1775 | 59 | 4634 | 248 |
Normative | 5585 | 27 | 604 | 41 | 3018 | 76 |
Source: from JASSS Volume 1, Issue 3, https://www.jasss.org/1/3/3.html
Table 4: Replication results | ||||||
Strategy | Str | st.dev. | St.Dev | st.dev. | Agg | st.dev |
Blind Aggression | 4848 | 38 | 1690 | 40 | 14134 | 139 |
Strategic | 5962 | 24 | 1967 | 36 | 5798 | 63 |
Normative | 7405 | 24 | 404 | 33 | 1809 | 61 |
Table 5: Private property and equal heritage (alphai = alphaj = 0.5) | ||||||
Strategy | Str | st.dev. | St.Dev | st.dev. | Agg | st.dev |
Blind Aggression | 4832 | 37 | 202 | 31 | 14153 | 125 |
Strategic | 5935 | 29 | 244 | 32 | 5844 | 76 |
Normative | 7387 | 27 | 77 | 10 | 1835 | 67 |
Table 6: Private property and unequal heritage (alphai = 0.9, alphaj = 0.1) | ||||||
Strategy | Str | st.dev. | St.Dev | st.dev. | Agg | st.dev |
Blind Aggression | 4852 | 34 | 7662 | 836 | 14059 | 130 |
Strategic | 5958 | 32 | 9304 | 1074 | 5790 | 67 |
Normative | 7404 | 29 | 11392 | 1227 | 1808 | 67 |
vt = 20 + beta (st-1 - 40) | (1) |
Table 7: Unequal renewal of resources (beta = 0.2) | ||||||
Strategy | Str | st.dev. | St.Dev | st.dev. | Agg | st.dev |
Blind Aggression | 5368 | 80 | 4832 | 116 | 18338 | 494 |
Strategic | 7755 | 40 | 6070 | 88 | 2333 | 75 |
Normative | 8569 | 20 | 2275 | 193 | 336 | 35 |
Table 8: Unequal renewal of resources (beta = 10.0) | ||||||
Strategy | Str | st.dev. | St.Dev | st.dev. | Agg | st.dev |
Blind Aggression | 6655 | 322 | 7651 | 216 | 9228 | 1104 |
Strategic | 8844 | 160 | 8453 | 176 | 241 | 31 |
Normative | 9096 | 189 | 7879 | 341 | 42 | 12 |
Table 9: Unequal renewal of resources (beta = 0.0375), time restriction removed | ||||||
Strategy | Str | st.dev. | St.Dev | st.dev. | Agg | st.dev |
Blind Aggression | 246394 | 3585 | 192707 | 22045 | 14114 | 141 |
Strategic | 280354 | 3986 | 224561 | 27327 | 5798 | 74 |
Normative | 842996 | 4552 | 331122 | 73152 | 1806 | 65 |
vt = 20 + pt-1 | (2) |
Table 10: Normative behavior from a sociological point of view; two sub-populations: Blind vs Normative (50:50) | ||||||||
Strategy | Str | st.dev. | St.Dev | st.dev. | Agg | st.dev | Pow | st.dev |
Society | 3647 | 111 | 2261 | 122 | 10352 | 1395 | ||
Out-Group: Blind | 3437 | 561 | 3038 | 174 | 7775 | 1164 | 10 | 0 |
In-Group: Normative | 3717 | 635 | 759 | 129 | 2757 | 415 | 209 | 20 |
Table 11: Normative behavior from a sociological point of view; two sub-populations: Strategic vs Normative (50:50) | ||||||||
Strategy | Str | st.dev. | St.Dev | st.dev. | Agg | st.dev | Pow | st.dev |
Society | 4116 | 61 | 2236 | 252 | 7651 | 416 | ||
Out-Group: Strategic | 6195 | 93 | 1149 | 172 | 3793 | 428 | 10 | 0 |
In-Group: Normative | 2086 | 461 | 584 | 129 | 3858 | 232 | 118 | 8 |
Key to tables 10 and 11:
The results are gathered from sets of 100 matches for each Strategy. The values shown are from left to right: The average of the agent's strength (Str) at the end of the match, the standard deviation of Str, the average of the standard deviation (St. Dev) of the agents' strength values at the end of the match, the standard deviation of St. Dev, the average number of aggressions (Agg) occuring during one match, the standard deviation of Agg, the average value of power (Pow) and the standard deviation of Pow.
COHEN A K, Lindesmith A and Schuessler K Eds. (1956) The Sutherland Papers. Bloomington: Indiana University Press.
CONTE R and Castelfranchi C (1995a) Understanding the functions of norms in social groups through simulation. In Gilbert N and Conte R (Eds.) Artificial Societies. The Computer Simulation of Social Life. London: UCL Press. pp. 252-267.
CONTE, R and Castelfranchi C (1995b) Cognitive and social action. London: UCL Press. pp. 74-118.
CONTE R and Castelfranchi C (1993) Norms as mental objects: From normative beliefs to normative goals.In Proceedings of MAAMAW'93. Neuchatel: Switzerland.
DAHRENDORF R (1962) On the Origin of Social Inequality. In Laslett P and Runciman W G (Eds.) Philosophy, Politics, and Society. Oxford: Basil Blackwell.
DURKHEIM E (1965 [1895] Regeln der soziologischen Methode. 2nd edition. Neuwied: Luchterhand.
DURKHEIM E (1966 [1893)] The division of labour in society. 3rd edition. New York: Free Press
GARFINKEL H (1967) Studies in Ethnomethodology. Englewood Cliffs, N.J.: Prentice-Hall.
GEIGER T (1962) Arbeiten zur Soziologie. Neuwied: Luchterhand.
HAFERKAMP H (1972) Kriminalität ist normal. Stuttgart: Enke.
HAFERKAMP H (1976) Soziologie als Handlungstheorie. 3rd edition. Opladen: Westdt. Verlag.
HAFERKAMP H (1980) Herrschaft und Strafrecht. Opladen: Westdt. Verlag.
HAFERKAMP H (1984) Herrschaftsverlust und Sanktionsverzicht. Kritische Bemerkungen zur Theorie des starken Staates, der neuen sozialen Kontrolle und des ideellen Abolitionismus. Kriminologisches Journal 15. pp. 112-131.
HAFERKAMP H (1987) Zur künftigen Neuorientierung der kriminologischen Forschung. Kriminologisches Journal 18. pp. 171-192.
HART H L A (1961) The concept of law. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
HEGSELMANN R, and Flache A (1998) Understanding complex social dynamics. A plea for cellular automata based modelling. Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation 1(3) <https://www.jasss.org/1/3/1.html>
KOHLBERG L (1969) Stage and Sequence: The cognitive development approach to socializatiion. In Goslin D A (Ed.) Handbook of socialization theory and research. Chicago: Rand McNelly College Publishing Co.
KOHLBERG L (1971) From is to ought. In Mischel Th (Ed.) Cognitive development and epistemology. New York: Academic Press.
LEWIS D (1969) Convention. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press.
MARX K (1936) Capital, a critique of political economy. The process of capitalist production, translated from the third German edition by S Moore and E Aveling. Edited by F Engels, revised and amplified according to the fourt German edition by E Untermann. New York: The Modern Library.
MERTON R K (1968) The Matthew effect in science. Science 159. pp. 56-63.
NONNER-WINKLER G (1984) Normen.In Kerber H and Schmieder A (Eds.). Handbuch Soziologie. Zur Theorie und Praxis sozialer Beziehungen. Reinbek: Rowohlt. pp. 398-408.
NOWAK A and Lewenstein M (1996) Modeling social change with cellular automata. In HEGSELMANN R, Mueller U and Troitzsch K G (Eds.) Modeling and Simulation in the Social Sciences from the Philosophy of Science Point of View. Dordrecht, Kluwer: pp. 249-286.
OPP K-D (1974) Abweichendes Verhalten und Gesellschaftsstruktur. Darmstadt: Luchterhand.
PARSONS T (1964) The Social System. New York: Routledge & Paul.
SCHELLING T C (1960) The strategy of conflict. Oxford: Oxford University Press.
SHERIF M (1967) Formation of social norms: The experimental paradigm. In Sherif M (1967) Social Interaction. Chicago: Aldine.
SHOHAM Y and Tenneholtz M (1992a) On the synthesis of useful social laws for artificial agent societies (preliminary report). In Proceedings of the AAAI Conference. pp. 276-281.
SHOHAM Y and Tenneholtz M (1992b) Emergent conventions in multi agent systems: Initial experimental results and observations. In Proceedings of the 3rd International Conference on KR&R. Cambridge, MA: pp. 225-232.
SUTHERLAND E H (1983 [1949]) White Collar Crime. The uncut version. New Haven: Yale Univ. Press.
SUTHERLAND E H and D R Cressey (1966) Principles of Criminology. 7th edition. Philadelphia: Lippincott.
ULLMAN-MARGALIT E (1977) The emergence of norms. Oxford: Clarendon Press.
VILA B J and Cohen L E (1993) Crime as Strategy. Testing an Evolutionary Ecological Theory of Expropriate Crime. American Journal of Sociology 98. pp. 873-912.
WALKER A and M Wooldridge (1995) Understanding the emergence of conventions in multi-agent systems. In Proceedings of ICMAS (International Joint Conference on Multi Agent Systems) San Francisco.
WEBER M (1960) Soziologische Grundbegriffe. In Weber M (1960) Wirtschaft und Gesellschaft. Tübingen: Mohr.
ZUCKERMAN H (1993) Die Werdegänge von Nobelpreisträgern. In Mayer K U (Ed.) Generationsdynamik in der Forschung. Frankfurt: Campus. pp. 59-79.
Return to Contents of this issue
© Copyright Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, 1998