© Copyright JASSS
Sergio Benvenuto (2000)
Fashion: Georg Simmel
Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation
vol. 3, no. 2,
<https://www.jasss.org/3/2/forum/2.html>
To cite articles published in the Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, please reference the above information and include paragraph numbers if necessary
Received: 26-Mar-00
Published: 31-Mar-00
Abstract
-
Georg Simmel's famous article on Fashion, published in 1904, is reviewed, and it is proposed that his analysis, especially in as much as it highlights the roles of both imitation and the need to make distinctions has contemporary relevance to simulation models and to mimetics.
- Keywords:
-
Georg Simmel, Theories of fashion, Simulation, Memetics
Introduction
-
- 1.1
- In the 20th century, much has been written on fashion, yet systematic
and general theories of fashion are few. The best remains one of the
earliest: Fashion by Georg Simmel.[1]
It is probably the only true attempt at a general theory of fashion and
although this paper is over a century old (it was published in 1895), it is
not yet passé.
- 1.2
- According to Simmel, fashion (non-cumulative change in cultural
features) derives from a basic tension specific to the social
condition of the human being. On one hand, each of us has tendency to
imitate others. On the other, we also have a tendency to
distinguish ourselves from others. Undoubtedly, some of us tend more
towards imitation (and thus to conformism) while others tend to distinction
(and thus to eccentricity and dissidence), but fashion's flux needs
both of these contradictory tendencies in order to work. In short,
Simmel argues that we need to postulate two radical drives which he
attributes to human nature.[2] Homo
Sapiens are driven by two instincts (among others) - one pushing them to
imitate their neighbours, the other pushing them to distinguish themselves.
From one side, an individual tends to imitate others they admire. From the
other, they tend to distinguish themselves from people towards whom they
are indifferent or who they despise.
- 1.3
- For Simmel "... fashion represents nothing more than one of the many
forms of life by the aid of which we seek to combine in uniform spheres of
activity the tendency towards social equalization with the desire for
individual differentiation and change." (F, p. 133) In each social relation
there are two forces at work: one pushing us to bind ourselves to others
through imitation, and another pushing us to unbind ourselves from others,
to undo the social network, through distinction. But social life changes in
so far as the balance between the socialising force and the de-socialising
force is always unstable and provisional. Fashion is an example of the way
in which actual social life always includes in some way its own opposite,
an asocial life. As Kant said, society is based on ungesellige
geselligkeit, "unsociable sociality".
- 1.4
- We can order the two sets of opposites (to which we add our own
proposals, indicated in blue) whose dynamic relationship produces
fashion:
Imitation |
Distinction |
Heredity |
Individual Variation |
Universality |
Particularity |
Submission |
Sense of Power |
Duration |
Mutability |
Femininity |
Masculinity |
Stillness |
Movement |
Receptivity |
Productivity |
Creation |
Destruction |
Darwinian Selection |
Darwinian Mutation |
Extensity |
Intensity |
Event |
Repetition |
Accident |
Meaning |
- 1.5
- Fashion is the effect of the dynamical play between these two batteries
of opposites. But fashion exists only in so far as one of the two poles
does not ultimately prevail in the end. Fashion is the effect of an always
unstable balance between two poles from which the self-destructive parabola
of fashion derives:
"As fashion spreads, it gradually goes to its doom. The
distinctiveness which in the early stages of a set fashion assures for it a
certain distribution is destroyed as the fashion spreads, and as this
element wanes, the fashion also is bound to die. (...) The attractions of
both poles of the phenomena meet in fashion, and show also here that they
belong together unconditionally, although, or rather because, they are
contradictory in their very nature." (F, pp. 138-139.)
- 1.6
- Now, the impulse to imitate - and thus to endure, to unify, to equalise
- is not directed towards our neighbours: we imitate instead people who
are, in one way or another, superior to us. From which follows the
Simmelian principle, "... fashion ... is a product of class distinction
..." (F, p. 133). For fashion to exist, society must be stratified, some
members must be perceived as inferior or superior - or simply as worthy or
unworthy of being imitated. And as far as the "inferior one" imitates their
direct "superior" and never vice versa, the conclusion is: "... fashion -
i.e., the latest fashion [in social forms, apparel, aesthetic
judgement, the whole style of human expression] - affects only the upper
classes." (F, p. 135.) For example, suppose some upper class girls begin to
wear a new skirt designed by a prestigious couturier. Soon, the desire for
lower class girls to imitate them will force the market to supply
low-priced copies. Thus, moving down from one level to another, in a short
space of time this skirt no longer distinguishes the upper class girls,
since everyone is wearing cheap imitations. So the girls from the upper
classes will once again have to look for something else to distinguish
themselves, which will once again be imitated, and so the cycle will goes
on.
- 1.7
- Even economists - who sooner or later have to take into consideration
fashion phenomena - consider a phenomenon called "snob demand". From an
economic point of view, fashion is a market constituted only of snobs -
essentially, a snob is a consumer who stops buying a product when the price
drops too much. Economists also talk about a "bandwagon effect" when a
product is sold more because of simple imitation. But there is also a
"reverse bandwagon effect", when a "snobbish" consumer stops buying a
product because too many others are buying it.[3] Every economic choice is bound not only to
the pure computational rationality of individuals, but is influenced by
"irrational" factors, i.e. by social imitation and by what Simmel calls the
"need for distinction", which is the contrary of imitation. Except that
while in economics the "reverse bandwagon effect" is limited to a specific
series of commodities, in fashion this effect is generalised and
constitutive of the fashion itself. We can say that what we call fashion -
a fast change of cultural features - is basically anything which
fundamentally depends on the game of bandwagon and reverse bandwagon, on
imitation and distinction. A game which does not concern just a small
portion of consumers - the snobs - but all or nearly all members of a
culture.
- 1.8
- Do we thus imitate persons who we admire and/or envy because we perceive
them to be superior? Moreover, does every fashion, in its distinctiveness,
display contempt towards our fellow citizens from whom we are
distinguishing ourselves? In other words, does fashion imply a relationship
between social envy and contempt? Simmel says: "... this
quiet personal usurpation of the envied property contains a kind of
antidote, which occasionally counter-acts the evil effects of this feeling
of envy." (F, p. 140.) In short, envy creates a social link - not in spite
its negative aspect, but precisely because of it. I can envy somebody only
if I admire them, to the degree that I make them my ideal of behaviour or
social achievement. Envy marks the distance between myself and my ideal of
being or having, when I see this ideal realised in my neighbour. But
fashion is also a remedy for envy, because, in imitating the person I
admire, I become or appear like them, and thus I identify myself as one who
appears admirable. Fashion dilutes envy among individuals by watering it
down with social inclusiveness.
Distinction, Imitation and Social Status
-
- 2.1
- But is the distinction versus imitation tension really
unshakeable? That is, must we absolutely suppose that there exists a small
group of persons which invent and create certain cultural traits by which
they aim only to distinguish themselves from a large mass of people
destined, at most, to imitate them?
- 2.2
- Even at the level of that innovating elite, not only is the drive to
distinguish oneself already at work, but the drive to imitate as well. For
example, even in the collaboration between Marx and Engels, we can say that
Engels in some ways imitated Marx. There are many other examples. Real
innovators without peers are few and far between. But the same is true in
fashion: one distinguishes oneself from the crowd by imitating some admired
and envied personality. On the other hand, even the millionth girl who
decides to cut her hair "according to the latest fashion" still
distinguishes herself: from her mother or from the girl next door who still
does not dare to do it.
- 2.3
- Distinction and imitation are thus two faces of the same coin: one
imitates an idealised other in order to distinguish oneself from the rest,
and also by changing ones imitative allegiance. Therefore the fashion
tension is not really structurally different in various cultural and social
classes; rather, only the extension of the distinction varies. In
short, the elite is characterised by the maximal extension of the
distinction: the type of hat or the aesthetic taste adopted by the elite is
distinct from almost all else, and for a while, the elite does something
unique. In the most prestigious and influential fashion shows - in
Milan, Paris, or New York - the great designers strive to present clothes
so eccentric that nobody will dare to wear them. Someone innocently
remarks, "what business sense is there in proposing clothes which nobody,
except for a very few snobs - and then only once - will wear?" In effect,
these big shows followed by the world press represent a distinctive
apex, the peak of a singular, distinctive uniqueness: those famous
models may well be the only ones in the world to wear those clothes
designed expressly to scandalise the "conventional folk". Yet the very same
designer has available more moderate, and less expensive, versions of the
same "idea" which he will sell to a wider market. In fact, they will have
available various models with decreasing "shock value", each fit to the
social area which can afford this given style.
- 2.4
- Female fashion - like every other kind - appears like a pyramid at whose
top one finds the supermodel exhibited in order to be imitated and yet
basically inimitable. Just as a creative genius offers him or herself to
imitation yet remains inimitable in their creativity, so the goddess-models
of our times embody this extreme distinction. The daring
outfits they wear do not prevent further imitation, but rather nourish it,
offering the unattainable paradigm which will inspire every consumer's
syntagms, that is, their compromises with daily banality.
- 2.5
- On the contrary, one becomes less and less elite and ever more a part of
the mass as the extension of ones differentiating ambition narrows. In this
ambit, fashion followers distinguish themselves at the most within their
offices, families or neighbourhoods. A person who is perceived by those in
a particular environment as being "one who follows the fashion"
distinguishes themselves in this environment, but their social rank is
still determined by the absolute dimensions of this environment from which
they seek to distinguish themselves.
- 2.6
- We might then substitute Simmel's distinction versus imitation
opposition with one more general, and hence more rich: the opposition
between intensity and extensity. When a novelty is absolute,
it has a maximum intensity, in the sense that it creates real, true
passions, be they positive or negative: scandal and enthusiasm, disgust and
love, anxiety and attraction. The novelty is perceived either as a serious
threat to our children or as salvation and revelation. As the novelty gains
in extension and loses its novelty, it loses its intensity and its
informative capacity. The theory of information in fact correlates the
increase of information with improbability: the more an event is
improbable, the more it appears meaningful and thus informative. As a
political belief (or the style for wearing a hat) spreads, an encounter
with this hat or that political belief becomes ever more probable and thus
increasingly less meaningful. What I call here extensity is the spreading
of a feature which corresponds with a proportional diminishing of
intensity.
- 2.7
- The lessening informational intensity of this feature owing to its
extension is correlated with the extension of the space or environment
where this ex-novelty is adopted. As previously mentioned, as a feature
propagates itself, it interests more and more individuals who aim to
distinguish themselves within an ever narrower social environment or scope.
In extending itself, the innovation loses intensity because it is adopted
in order to produce intensity (distinction, that is information) in ever
narrower contexts.
- 2.8
- In fact, an idea or custom has its maximal innovative intensity - its
maximal significance - when it is still restricted to a small group. For
example, polls and inquiries carried out among the young and students
between 1967-1970 in countries where youth and student protest movements
were exploding - such as Italy, France and West Germany - showed that, in
fact, quite moderate or even conservative ideas and mentalities prevailed
amongst them in this period. Indeed, during these years, the ideas of the
protest movements reached their greatest intensity, yet it was precisely
because of this that they were not very extensive. At that time, Daniel
Cohn-Bendit in France theorised on the role of the "minorité
agissante". Even amongst the young, it was a minority that was
responsible for the big movements that turned France upside down. Yet these
minorities at the time felt they were riding a wave, and that they were
producing great intensities in relation to their context. At that time, in
fact, the difference in styles of dressing - not to mention thinking -
between the young and the not-so-young widened. This split was especially
notable in Great Britain, which produced a type of pop music which marked
an epoch probably because it embodied a radical distinction between
the old and the young, past and present, tradition and innovation. Do those
English songs appear today as "classics" because of their intrinsic
quality? There is nothing more disputable than the intrinsic quality of an
artistic creation. Even today, we can listen to songs - like "All You Need
is Love" or "(I Can't Get No) Satisfaction" - with a certain emotion
because they carry, even if attenuated by the impact of time, a certain
distinctive force.
- 2.9
- When at the end of the seventies - the "flowing back years" as they were
called in Continental Europe - sociologists interviewed the young people of
that epoch, they realised that the principles and exigencies of the elite
which had played an active role in 1967-1970 had now been assumed by the
majority of youth, although in less radical forms.[4]
Anti-Fashion
-
- 3.1
- The theory that fashion creators always belong to the upper social
classes is often contested. Instead, it is well known - and often said -
that many fashions taken up by snobs come from the humblest origins. For
example, blue jeans originated as the humble pants of American cowboys and
gold miners. And Western-style male dressing - which comes down to us from
the nineteenth century - derives from the Quakers' attire, not from the
Court aristocracy, which means that it derived from the fashion of an
oft-derided religious group. Much of the slang spoken by social fringe
groups becomes fashionable. The classical French argot was the
language of the underworld. Simmel himself realised this when he spoke
about the demi-monde, the underworld:
"The fact that the demi-monde is so frequently a pioneer in
matters of fashion, is due to its peculiarly uprooted form of life. The
pariah existence to which society condemns the demi-monde, produces an open
or latent hatred against everything that has the sanction of law, of every
permanent institution ... In this continual striving for new, previously
unheard-of fashions, in the regardlessness with which the one that is most
diametrically opposed to the existing one is passionately adopted, there
lurks an aesthetic expression of the desire for destruction, which seems to
be an element peculiar to all that lead this pariah-like existence, so long
as they are not completely enslaved within." (F, p. 145.)
- 3.2
- Gangsters and those on the fringes have a destructive impulse because
they nourish an intolerance - whose origins can be sociological or purely
personal - for order, repetition and univocal meaning.
- 3.3
- Anyway, historical research shows that these features of the lower or
fringe classes very probably become fashionable only once they are adopted
by certain social elites, that is, by social strata furthest from the
fringe. Simmel grasps very well the "exotic origin of fashion". In some
societies and eras, a sub-group might borrow a feature from a completely
different society:
"Because of their external origin, these imported fashions
create a special and significant form of socialization, which arises
through mutual relation to a point without the circle. It sometimes appears
as though social elements, just like the axes of vision, converge best at a
point that is not too near." (F, p. 136.)
- 3.4
- When a trendy male wears jeans and in so doing "promotes" them as
Western dress, he is borrowing a feature which is basically foreign with
respect to his higher social class. The snob borrows a cultural feature not
from those who lie at the bottom of the social hierarchy, but from those
who appear outside the hierarchy altogether; snobs, in imitating
those lying outside their class, proclaim their own special relation to the
social pyramid whose peak they occupy (or aim to).
- 3.5
- The main fashion agents - such as artists, women and the young - are
probably "the privileged ones" in so far as they represent, in the social
whole, the agency of maximal distinction, they represent
within that society that other than society, that which most
distinguishes itself from society. But in so far as these incarnations of
distinction are largely imitated, they carry out the real function of
fashion: the incessant re-socialisation of the asocial. Fashion -
basing itself on the imitation above all of those who do everything
possible to distinguish themselves from others - socialises what could
disrupt the sociality itself. Fashion is a process by which the society
consolidates itself by reintegrating what disrupts it.
Fashion in the Middle
-
- 4.1
- One aspect of this imitation-distinction dualism, according to Simmel,
is the tension between socialism and individualism. In effect, Simmel did
not have the experience, as we do today, of mature democratic political
systems. Everyone today believes that a democracy enters into maturity when
it produces an alternation between ideological forces deriving roughly from
a socialism of solidarity on the one hand and from capitalist individualism
on the other. This boring alternation usually results in a low voter turn
out. In some way, this eternal oscillation between left and right in our
elective democracies realises what the oscillating cycles of fashion do on
the level of clothing and furnishing: in each case, a basic dualism in
social life is at work. And like fashion - which often oscillates between
two opposite poles - even Western political systems find their stability
precisely in a continuous oscillation between contiguous political
forces, which nonetheless present themselves as opposed and thus
alternative. Democracy triumphed over totalitarianism because it
gave room to government fashions, while totalitarianism was obliged
to freeze the system and lose flexibility. So fashion also offers a model
for a social dialectics - between cohesion and fragmentation - which is
typical of modern societies.
- 4.2
- "It is peculiarly characteristic of fashion ...", Simmel writes, "...
that it renders possible a social obedience, which at the same time is a
form of individual differentiation." (F, p. 141.) Fashion exists because,
in conforming, we differentiate ourselves, and in differentiating
ourselves, we are essentially conforming. But this is exactly the
proclaimed ideal of every modern democracy. Democracy calls on everyone's
opinion, giving room even to extreme, de-socialising and subversive
opinions, yet it is precisely in giving space to idiosyncratic ideas that
it aims towards social cohesion. This is what has been called, since Adam
Smith, the Invisible Hand: order and stability are born precisely by giving
free rein to disorder, the unstable and the fringe. Fashion's extraordinary
and sometimes ostentatious development during these last years can thus be
seen as a corollary of the success of the Western democratic model and its
values.
- 4.3
- The alternation between left and right, typical of mature democracies,
is an alternation between two "centres" or "middles". A slightly
left-centre dominance is replaced by a slightly right-centre dominance, and
vice versa. Even fashion is usually centrist or moderate.
Except in critical periods involving a violent change of habits - as
probably happened at the end of the eighteenth century when the American
and French revolutions rapidly changed ways of dressing, or in China during
the Cultural Revolution - fashion oscillations are never radical. The
famous couturiers propose extreme designs that nobody will actually wear,
but the mass of people will allow themselves to be more or less influenced
by this, and will end up wearing milder versions of these extreme
proposals. In this way, over the centuries, the manner of dressing changes
in quite showy ways, but the intermediate steps are small and oscillating.
In fashion as in politics, revolutions are rare, while the incessant, slow
reforming work goes on.
Simmel's Theory and Simulation
-
- 5.1
- An essay of this sort has an obvious importance for simulation
techniques. Simulation as applied to the social sciences is usually limited
to considering imitative aspects: how individuals aggregate together, and
under what conditions. Only rarely have simulators sought to represent this
dialectic between imitation and distinction which Simmel so rightly pointed
out.
- 5.2
- Furthermore, Simmel's analysis goes beyond the albeit wide scope of
fashion, and invests all forms of social transmission and change, whenever
there emerges not only the need to imitate, obey the rules, or conform to
others, but also the opposite: the need to distinguish or individualise
oneself. Economists have already found similar phenomena in the field of
economic behaviour, but we could find that same tension of "imitation
versus distinction" in many other aspects of social life. To find a program
with which to simulate this dialectic in fact presents noteworthy
difficulties, yet simulation techniques would be making an important
advance were they to discover a method of representing this dynamic.
- 5.3
- Simmel's analysis is also capable of making a notable contribution -
probably in a critical and negative sense - to a currently expanding sector
of study today, that of memetics. As is known, memetics attempts a
reconstruction in exquisitely Darwinian terms - that is, in terms of
mutation and natural selection - of cultural processes. That is, memetics
bets on an isomorphism between processes regarding genetic replicants and
cultural ones. As we already pointed out, Simmel's hypothesis seemingly
reveals an isomorphism between cultural change and biological evolution:
the tension between imitation and distinction recalls the Darwinian tension
between selection and mutation. Yet at the same time, Simmel implies the
efficacy of a primary instinct - that of distinguishing oneself - of which
we are hard put to find an equivalent in non-human species, and which
apparently does not ensure evident reproductive advantages to the
individual's genes. In each case, this theory of Simmel - as ignored in the
Anglo-American countries as it is famous in Italy - lends itself well to
the debate both within memetics as well as to the supporters and critics of
the memetic hypothesis. In this way, Simmel's theory might be able to
bridge these two sectors of study - memetics and simulation - which have
heretofore not done much in the way of collaboration.
Notes
-
1 Georg Simmel, "Fashion", International
Quarterly, 10(1), October 1904, pp. 130-155, reprinted in
American Journal of Sociology, 62(6), May 1957, pp. 541-558.
Quotations used here are taken from the October 1904 translation and
labelled F.
2 These drives must be "natural" and cannot
be sociologically produced because they are asserted to be the cause, and
not the effect, of social phenomena.
3 Veblen was the first to remark, in 1899
(The Theory of the Leisure Class, Modern Library, Random House, New
York 1934), that, in a market, what and whether one buys is
determined partially by what and whether many others have also bought. In
short, demand by the consumer is bound partially to interpersonal effects.
On this point, see also: James Duesenberry, Income, Savings and the
Theory of Consumer Behavior, Harvard University Press, Cambridge MA,
1949; Harvey Leibenstein, "Bandwagon, Snob and Veblen Effects in the Theory
of Consumer Demand", Quarterly Journal of Economics, 64,
1950, pp. 183-207 and Harvey Leibenstein, Beyond Economic Man: A New
Foundation for Microeconomics, Harvard University Press, Cambridge MA,
1976; Mark Granovetter and Roland Soong, "Threshold Models of Interpersonal
Effects in Consumer Demand", Journal of Economic Behavior and
Organization, 7, 1986, pp. 83-99.
4 For the case of Italy, see: C. Tullio
Altan, I Valori Difficili, Bompiani, Milano, 1974; L. Ricolfi and L.
Sciolla, Senza Padri n&ecaute; Maestri, De Donato, Bari, 1980; L.
Ricolfi and L. Sciolla, "Fermare il Tempo" in Inchiesta, 54,
1981, pp. 34-43; S. Messina, "I partiti, la Famiglia, il Lavoro: Ecco che
Cosa ne Pensano i Giovani", La Repubblica, 17 giugno 1983, p.
6.
Return to Contents of this issue
© Copyright Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, 1998