Armano Srbljinovic, Drazen Penzar, Petra Rodik and Kruno Kardov (2003)
An Agent-Based Model of Ethnic Mobilisation
Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation
vol. 6, no. 1
To cite articles published in the Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, please reference the above information and include paragraph numbers if necessary
<https://www.jasss.org/6/1/1.html>
Received: 16-Nov-2002 Accepted: 15-Jan-2003 Published: 31-Jan-2003
mi(t+1) = mi(t) + (miapp + misocnet + micool)Δt, | (1) |
(2) |
in which gri denotes the grievance degree of agent i,[9] and kapp is a constant, which together with the values of the second coefficient ksame/other/neutral, enables us to control the magnitude of miapp, i.e. to control agent i's 'susceptibility to appeals'. As we can see in (2), we distinguish between agents' susceptibilities to appeals issued from the sources of the 'same', the 'other', and the 'grey' colour. It is generally assumed that, all other things being equal, the effect of an appeal is stronger on the agents of the same colour as the appeal's source, than on the agents of other colour. Consequently, the values of ksame are greater than the values of kother. It is also assumed that the effect of 'a neutral appeal' is generally smaller than the effect of 'brethren's appeals', but still stronger than the effect of 'appeals of the others'. Finally, regarding the effects of neutral appeals, it is assumed that these effects are proportional to the intensity of civic (not the ethnic) mobilisation, so the factor mi(t) is in the case of neutral appeals replaced with 1 - mi(t).
(3) |
in which ksocne is the coefficient controlling the magnitude of misocnet, netsize is the size of the network, i.e. the number of agents comprising the social network of agent i, and impsame, impother are impacts coming from the agents of the same and other colour, respectively. More precisely, the formula for the impact of those agents in the network that have the same colour as agent i is:
(4) |
in which Nsame is the number of such agents. The formula for the impact of those agents in the network that have colour different than the colour of agent i is:
(5) |
in which Nother is the number of such agents.
(6) |
in which kcool is the coefficient controlling the magnitude of micool. This ensures that cooling increases exponentially with mobilisation intensity, that it is very small for small mobilisation intensities, and that it is zero for the mobilisation intensity of zero.[12]
Figure 1. Visualisation of agents using a SWARM-based GUI |
Figure 2. Some of the typical outcomes produced by variation in agents' initial mobilisation intensity and in agents' social connections, at the frequency of red appeals 3 and the frequency of neutral appeals 4 |
Table 1: Distribution of outcomes according to their types, when varying the value of probability p of having a friend of a different colour | |||||||||
p | Number of outcomes of type: | ||||||||
I | II | III | IV | V | VI | VII | VIII | IX | |
0.1 | 7 | 93 | - | - | - | - | - | - | - |
0.2 | 30 | 70 | - | - | - | - | - | - | - |
0.3 | 39 | 61 | - | - | - | - | - | - | - |
0.4 | 49 | 34 | 12 | 4 | 1 | - | - | - | - |
0.5 | 51 | 16 | 12 | 6 | 4 | 9 | 2 | - | - |
0.6 | 55 | 41 | 1 | - | 1 | - | 1 | 1 | - |
0.7 | 51 | 47 | 1 | - | - | - | - | - | 1 |
Figure 3. Some of the patterns observed when dispersing grievance values |
Figure 4. The example of change of an outcome with the change in blue frequency from none (left) to 200 (right) (default value kother = 0.25) |
To avoid this confusion with 'nations' and 'nationalities', and taking into account that the (non)possession of political rights is not of particular importance for our model, in the remainder of this paper we will mostly use the more basic term 'ethnic'. By using this term, we do not mean that nations of the former Yugoslavia are mere ethnic groups and not nations, neither that they are nations less than other nations are. On the contrary, by using this term we want to emphasise that ethnicity is a universal human characteristic.
2 Except for the fact that Montenegro and Serbia stayed together in the same state, the status of which is currently in the process of redefinition.
3 In discussing four distinct classes of 'causes of conflict': actions of political entrepreneurs, political processes and institutions, international influences, and broader societal conditions, we closely follow Lund (2001). We also agree that: "The point of laying out these four types of explanation is not that one or another approach will necessarily be the single correct one. It is rather that in approaching a given conflict, analysts […] may need to consider several kinds of variables." (ibid., p. 135). It is also likely that not all the conflicts in the region of former Yugoslavia were equally influenced by particular factors. An enquiry with the scope much broader than ours would be needed to determine the importance of each group of factors in each particular case.
4 To use Posner's metaphor (Posner 2000), the problem that Banton refers to may be likened to tuning stations on a radio device and may be further broken into two components: first, changing the radio station, i.e. choosing particular (ethnic) identity among possible others, and second, turning up the volume at which particular station plays, i.e. increasing the degree of importance of that identity. This work deals mainly with the second component of this problem.
5 Some cases of ethnic mobilisation in the former Yugoslavia, particularly in Bosnia and Herzegovina, involved simultaneous mobilisation of more than two different ethnic groups. However, as we shall see, even the two-sides model becomes soon very complex, so, for the sake of simplicity, we have not considered modelling of more than two groups so far.
6 Having only two 'rival attributes' is also a simplification. In the particular case of former Yugoslavia, other attributes existed, like religion and membership in the Yugoslav communist party. Religious affiliation (to Islamic, Orthodox and Catholic church) was consistent with ethnic divides and generally played a mobilising role. Membership in a unified Yugoslav communist party spread over all nations and republics, but did not play a moderating role to the conflict. The party instantly broke down along ethnic borders like all other federal institutions.
7 The discussion of a relationship between grievance and mobilisation intensities is continuing in Section5.
8 For a particularly vivid account of the so-called 'Meetings of Truth' accompanying Slobodan Milosevic's ethnic mobilisation campaign that he called 'Anti-Bureaucratic Revolution' see (Silber and Little 1997, pp. 58-69).
9 For the sake of model's simplicity, at this research stage we hold grievance degrees constant during simulation experiments.
10 For the sake of model's simplicity, at this research stage agents use only information about colour and mobilisation intensity of the members of their social network; information about grievance degrees is not used.
11 More precisely, we use the sum of the two. We have done some experiments with the maximum of the two instead of the sum, but have not observed significant differences in results.
12 The choice of this particular 'cooling function' is rather arbitrary. We were primarily led by a desire to keep it relatively simple. Possible model's extensions, discussed in the last section of this paper, may also include experimenting with other functional forms.
13 Choosing the relatively small total number of agents was mainly dictated by the limited computing power at our disposal (Pentium II on 266 MHz).
14 In order to start with as simple model as possible, we chose not to disperse the grievance variable as default.
15 In fact, as we can control the probability with which agents possess friends of a different colour, the 'random assignment' here means that the members of social networks are randomly chosen, and that this is done so that the probability of having a 'friend' of other colour is 0.5.
16 Note that there are two sources of randomness in the default setting: the initial mobilisation intensity and the layout of social networks.
17 I.e. the frequency (in simulation periods) with which the appeals are issued.
18 This 'perfect observability of appeals' can be justified on the grounds that in modern communications era it becomes increasingly difficult to 'hide' mobilising appeals to the own group from 'others'.
19 It is important to observe that this grouping does not reflect agents' actual positions in social networks, i.e. 'geographic proximity' in this representation does not imply membership in neighbours' social networks. The only purpose of the grouping was to facilitate visual inspection of changing mobilisation levels in time.
20 On the other hand, varying the size of the networks did not produce significant effects, which is also easily justified by the fact that the network's influence is normalised with network's size in (4).
21 Reflected in frequency values of issuing coloured and neutral appeals, respectively.
22 I.e., close to the default initial average mobilisation of 0.5.
23 With probabilities of having a friend of a different colour 0.1, 0.2 and 0.3.
24 Settings with probabilities of having a friend of a different colour greater than 0.5 are rather artificial in the sense that such an ethnic group could probably not exist in reality in a long term, as contacts among its members would be too rare to enable sustainability of the group's identity. This is also the reason why we did not experiment with the most extreme values of p: 0.8 and 0.9. However, more rigorous sensitivity analyses in the future may include those experimental settings also.
25 Probability of having a friend of a different colour was again on default value of 0.5
26 There seem to be no obstacles for the simulation time periods to be interpreted as needed: as hours, days, weeks, months or whatever. Determining the right time scale depends mainly on how fast are the real mobilisation processes that we want to refer to. The model seems also to be general enough to allow similar scalability in spatial dimension, i.e. in the number of represented agents.
BAK P (1996) How Nature Works: The Science of Self-Organized Criticality. New York: Copernicus.
BANTON M (1994) Modelling Ethnic and National Relations. Ethnic and Racial Studies, 17(1), pp. 1-18.
CEDERMAN L E (1997) Emergent Actors in World Politics: How States & Nations Develop & Dissolve. Princeton: Princeton University Press.
CEDERMAN L E (2001a) Nationalism and Bounded Integration: What It Would Take to Construct a European Demos. European Journal of International Relations, 7(2), pp. 139-174.
CEDERMAN L E (2001b) Nationalist Systems Change and its Geographic Consequences. Paper prepared for the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, San Francisco,http://www.sas.upenn.edu/brownecip/Cederman.doc.
CRAWFORD B (1998) "Explaining Cultural Conflict in Ex-Yugoslavia: Institutional Weakness, Economic Crisis, and Identity Politics". In Crawford B, Lipschutz R D (Eds.), The Myth of "Ethnic Conflict": Politics, Economics and "Cultural Violence". Berkeley: University of California.
FORBES H D (1997) Ethnic Conflict: Commerce, Culture and the Contact Hypothesis. New Haven and London: Yale University Press.
GURR T R (1998) "A Risk Assessment Model of Ethnopolitical Rebellion". In Davies J L, Gurr T R (Eds.), Preventive Measures: Building Risk Assessment and Crisis Early Warning Systems. Lanham: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers, Inc.
HAMMOND R (2000) Endogenous Transition Dynamics in Corruption: An Agent-Based Computer Model. Center on Social and Economic Dynamics working paper,http://www.brook.edu/es/dynamics/papers/ross/ross.pdf.
LUND M S (2001) "Why Are Some Ethnic Disputes Settled Peacefully, While Others Become Violent? Comparing Slovakia, Macedonia , and Kosovo". In Alker H R, Gurr T R, Rupesinghe K (Eds.), Journeys Through Conflict - Narratives And Lessons, Lanham: Rowman & Littlefield Publishers, Inc.
LUSTICK I S (2000) Agent-Based Modelling of Collective Identity: Testing Constructivist Theory. Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, vol. 3, no. 1,https://www.jasss.org/3/1/1.html.
MOORE W H and Jaggers K (1990) Deprivation, Mobilization and the State: A Synthetic Model of Rebellion. Journal of Developing Societies, 6(1), pp. 17-36,http://garnet.acns.fsu.edu/~whmoore/researchpapers.html.
PELLET A (1992) The Opinions of the Badinter Arbitration Committee: A Second Breath for the Self-Determination of Peoples. European Journal of International Law, 3(1), pp. 178-185.
PENZAR D and Srbljinovic A (2002) Dynamic Modeling of Ethnic Conflicts. Paper presented at the 16th triennial conference of the International Federation of Operational Research Societies, University of Edinburgh, July 8-12,http://www.ffzg.hr/hsd/polemos/modeling-ethnic-conflicts2.doc.
POSNER D N (2000) Measuring Ethnic Identities and Attitudes Regarding Inter-group Relations: Methodological Pitfalls and a New Technique. Paper presented to LiCEP workshop, University of Pennsylvania, October 20-22,http://www.duke.edu/web/licep/2/posner/posner.pdf.
SILBER L and Little A (1997) Yugoslavia: Death of a Nation (revised and updated edition). New York: Penguin Books USA Inc.
SZAYNA T A (Ed.) (2000) Identifying Potential for Ethnic Conflict: Application of a Process Model. Santa Monica: RAND.
TURCOTTE D L (1999) Self-Organized Criticality. Reports on Progress in Physics 62, pp. 1377-1429.
WOODWARD S L (1995) Balkan Tragedy: Chaos and Dissolution after the Cold War. Washington D.C.: The Brookings Institution.
Return to Contents of this issue
© Copyright Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, [2003]