Stephen Younger (2004)
Reciprocity, Normative Reputation, and the Development of Mutual Obligation in Gift-Giving Societies
Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation
vol. 7, no. 1
To cite articles published in the Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, please reference the above information and include paragraph numbers if necessary
<https://www.jasss.org/7/1/5.html>
Received: 03-Aug-2003 Accepted: 12-Dec-2003 Published: 31-Jan-2004
Table 1: Contributions to the agent quality factor and the interaction matrix | |
Quality factor | Increased by one unit per timestep |
Decreased one unit if need for hunger >100 | |
Decreased one unit if need for sleep >50 | |
Decreased one unit if need for companionship > 48 | |
Decreased one unit if need for activity > 96 | |
Increased five units if new fact sensed | |
Increased one unit if fact given or received | |
Increased by twenty percent of goods shared | |
Increased by ten percent of amount of goods received in sharing event | |
Decreased by ten percent of goods stolen from this agent | |
Increased by 100 units on first mating if family enabled | |
Increased by twenty units per mating | |
Increased by ten percent of agents deposited at home shelter | |
Increased by one unit if exploring landscape | |
Interaction matrix | Increased one point per fact given to another |
Increased one point per fact received from another | |
Increased by ten percent of goods received in sharing | |
Increased by twenty percent of goods given to another | |
Increased by ten percent of goods taken from another | |
Decreased by ten percent of goods taken from self by another | |
Increased by one hundred points for first mating | |
Increased by twenty points per mating | |
Set to 100 for offspring at birth | |
Set to 90 for parents of offspring at birth | |
Table 2: Results for a simulation of 30 sharing and 30 stealing agents acting for 4000 timesteps. One theft permanently set the character of the stealing agents. Standard deviations are given in parentheses. Castelfranchi et al (1998) used a different method for tracking agent strength, but the results are qualitatively similar in that normative agent strength increased while aggressive agent strength decreased upon the communication of normative reputation | ||
Scenario | Normative Agent Strength | Aggressive Agent Strength |
MH0000 | -791 | 901 |
(213) | (213) | |
MH00N0 | -466 | 574 |
(122) | (122) | |
Castelfranchi et al (1998) No communication | 3764 | 5973 |
Castelfranchi et al (1998) With communication | 4734 | 4968 |
Table 3: Results for Ten Lifetime Runs (Standard deviations in parentheses) | ||||||||||
Scenario | Age/ Hunger Ratio | Strength Sharing Agents | Strength Non-Sharing Agents | Quality Factor Sharing Agents | Quality Factor Non-Sharing Agents | Obligation Factor Sharing Agents | Obligation Factor Non-Sharing Agents | Sharing Rate | Stealing Rate | Flight Rate |
MH0000 | 0.607 | -160 | 201 | 1520 | 1260 | N/A | N/A | 0.00219 | 0.00264 | N/A |
(No rep) | (0.103) | (29) | (30) | (85) | (43) | (0.00016) | (0.00009) | |||
MH0000 | 0.513 | -133 | 170 | 1410 | 1180 | 890 | 360 | 0.00224 | 0.00253 | 0 |
(0.020) | (7.5) | (12) | (78) | (44) | (28) | (6.2) | (.00013) | (.00005) | 0 | |
MH000T | 0.77 | -197 | 239 | 1020 | 399 | 805 | 318 | 0.00333 | 0.00282 | 0.0287 |
(0.055) | (27) | (34) | (62) | (26) | (31) | (12) | (0.00061) | (.00031) | (0.0049) | |
MH00N0 | 0.55 | -167 | 193 | 1500 | 1180 | 2760 | 1880 | 0.00222 | 0.00274 | 0 |
(0.049) | (36) | (32) | (63) | (29) | (51) | (31) | (0.00025) | (0.00016) | 0 | |
MH00NT | 0.578 | -159 | 206 | 1230 | 918 | 2650 | 1830 | 0.00257 | 0.00260 | 0.0397 |
(0.073) | (16) | (23) | (71) | (74) | (120) | (99) | (0.00025) | (0.00011) | (0.0027) | |
MHFL00 | 1.70 | -383 | 404 | 1630 | 1280 | N/A | N/A | 0.00604 | 0.00396 | N/A |
(No rep) | (0.55) | (122) | (153) | (137) | (75) | (0.00057) | (0.00012) | |||
MHFL00 | 1.35 | -257 | 322 | 1540 | 1210 | 1150 | 517 | 0.00585 | 0.00389 | 0 |
(0.24) | (24) | (35) | (18) | (32) | (26) | (7) | (0.00074) | (0.00015) | 0 | |
MHFL0T | 1.66 | -228 | 289 | 995 | 382 | 1040 | 479 | 0.00554 | 0.00349 | 0.0323 |
(0.33) | (26) | (39) | (31) | (39) | (27) | (13) | (0.00059) | (0.00013) | (0.0026) | |
MHFLN0 | 1.44 | -282 | 352 | 1580 | 1250 | 3970 | 2820 | 0.00582 | 0.00406 | 0 |
(0.17) | (44) | (45) | (68) | (43) | (153) | (104) | (0.00069) | (0.00011) | 0 | |
MHFLNT | 1.14 | -247 | 290 | 1170 | 787 | 3770 | 2640 | 0.00559 | 0.00370 | 0.0177 |
(0.12) | (30) | (10) | (93) | (135) | (134) | (116) | (0.00044) | (0.00011) | (0.0056) | |
MH0000: | Home shelter, no family, no leadership, no communication of normative reputation, no flight | |||||||||
MHFLNT: | Home shelter, family structure, leadership, communication of normative reputation, flight | |||||||||
No rep: | No memory of normative reputation | |||||||||
EKEH P (1974) Social Exchange Theory, Cambridge: Harvard University Press.
FIRTH R (1927) The Study of Primitive Economics, Economica 0, 312-335.
GOWDY J (Ed) (1998), Limited Wants, Unlimited Means: A Reader on Hunter-Gatherer Economics and the Environment, Washington DC: Island Press.
HALES D (2002) Group Reputation Supports Beneficent Norms. Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation 5 (4). <https://www.jasss.org/5/4/4.html >.
HOMANS G C (1958) Social Behavior as Exchange. American Journal of Sociology 63, 597-606.
JAFFE K (2002) An Economic Analysis of Altruism: Who Benefits from Altruistic Acts? Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation 5 (3). <https://www.jasss.org/5/3/3.html >.
KEELEY LH (1996) War Before Civilization, New York: Oxford University Press.
KOLLOCK P (1993) "An Eye for an Eye Leaves Everyone Blind": Cooperation and Accounting Systems, American Sociological Review 58, 768-786.
MACY M W and Willer W (2002) From Factors to Actors: Computational Sociology and Agent-Based Modeling, Annual Review of Sociology 28, 143-166.
MALINOWSKI B (1984) Argonauts of the Western Pacific, Prospect Heights: Waveland Press.
MAUSS M (1990) The Gift: Form and Reason for Exchange in Archaic Societies, New York: Norton.
POSPISIL L (1958) Kapauku Papuans and Their Law, Yale Publications in Anthropology No. 54. (p57)
RIDLEY M (1998) The Origins of Virtue: Human Instincts and the Evolution of Cooperation, New York: Penguin.
SAAM N J and Harrer A (1999) Simulating Norms, Social Inequality, and Functional Change in Artificial Societies. Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation 2 (1). <https://www.jasss.org/2/1/2.html >.
SAHLINS M (1972) Stone Age Economics, Aldine de Gruyter, New York. (p191)
YELLEN J E (1998) "The Transformation of the Kalahari !Kung". In Gowdy J (Ed), Limited Wants, Unlimited Means: A Reader on Hunter-Gatherer Economics and the Environment, Washington DC: Island Press.
YOUNGER S M (2002) Discrete Agent Modeling as a Tool for the Study of Individual and Social Development: The MICROS Code (Version 8.0), Los Alamos National Laboratory Report LA-UR-02-7009 <http://lib-www.lanl.gov/cgi-bin/getfile?00852082.pdf>.
YOUNGER S M (2003) Discrete Agent Simulations of the Effect of Simple Social Structures on the Benefits of Resource Sharing, Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation 6 (3). <https://www.jasss.org/6/3/1.html >.
Return to Contents of this issue
© Copyright Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, [2004]