Sophie Thoyer, Sylvie Morardet, Patrick Rio, Leo Simon, Rachel Goodhue and Gordon Rausser (2001)
A Bargaining Model to Simulate Negotiations between Water Users
Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation
vol. 4, no. 2,
To cite articles published in the Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, please reference the above information and include paragraph numbers if necessary
<https://www.jasss.org/4/2/6.html>
Received: 01-Nov-00 Accepted: 01-Feb-01 Published: 31-Mar-01
Figure 1. Simplified representation of the multilateral bargaining model from Adams et al. (1996) |
Figure 2. Projects for new dams in the Adour river basin |
Natural water stock + stock provided by will-be dams + stock provided by existing dams - water used by basins which are not included in the negotiation - total quotas given to farmers = residual stock in the river
residual stock in the river > crisis stockHydraulic models have been developed in order to estimate natural flows for a set of climatic years.
Sum for all three sub-basins (Quotas * Price) (operating and maintenance costs of new damsOperating and maintenance costs have been estimated on the basis of data for existing dams as a function of the new dam capacities.
with π aggregate profit in million francs in sub-basin i
P price of water in francs/m3
Q total quota given to the sub-basin (in million m3)
with D residual flow in the downstream basin. DC3 is assigned a different coefficient from DC1 + DC2 because the third dam would be located in the mountains and there is a stronger aversion for this dam due to landscape preservation concerns than for the first two dams.
with C operating and maintenance costs in million francs
MaxQ maximum sum of quotas which can be allocated given the exogenous constraints
MaxDC maximum dam capacity
MaxLoss : maximum potential losses by the manager
Table 1: reference simulation | |
Reference simulation : 7 players, equal weights | |
Upstream quota | 1665 m3/ha |
Midstream quota | 2501 m3/ha |
Downstream quota | 2787 m3/ha |
Dam capacity 1 (in millions m3) | 5 Mm3 |
Dam capacity 2 (in millionsm3)) | 0 Mm3 |
Dam capacity 3 (in millions m3)) | 14 Mm3 |
Water price (FF/m3) | 0.077 |
Quantity of water left in the river | 11 m3/s |
Crisis discharge | 2.8 m3/s |
Figure 3. Negotiation outcomes when the political weight of farmers increases |
Figures 4 and 5. Negotiation outcomes when the political weight of environmentalists increases |
Figure 6. Negotiation outcomes when the political weight of the taxpayer increases |
Figure 7. Negotiation outcomes when the political weight of the manager increases |
Figure 8. Trajectories of negotiation outcomes |
Figure 9. Changes in water prices when players' political weights change |
Figure 10. Negotiation outcomes for three negotiation structures - landscape environmentalist |
Note: negotiation variables are standardised and the axis scales are all identical
Table 2: Characteristics of the three initial proposals | |||||||
Qu (m3/ha) | Qm | Qd | DC1 (Mm3) | DC2 | DC3 | P (FF/m3) | |
Proposal 1 | 1300 | 1500 | 1500 | 5 | 20 | 20 | 0.04 |
Proposal 2 | 1300 | 1500 | 1500 | 5 | 0 | 20 | 0.04 |
Proposal 3 | 1800 | 1800 | 1800 | 5 | 20 | 20 | 0.04 |
Figure 11. Negotiation outcomes for three different initial proposals |
2 generally, at the scale of a catchment basin
3 such as obligation to nature and to future generation
4 For example, the case of an agricultural producer over-pumping water in the river will be denounced by environmentalists. On the other hand, excess water spread on the field might percolate and improve the level of the watertable. Therefore externalities for other water users are both positive and negative.
5 Such as the condition of "beneficial use" in the Californian water right system.
6 Schéma Directeur d'Aménagement et de Gestion des Eaux
7 Schéma d'Aménagement et de Gestion des Eaux
8 Irrigated areas theoretically get specific CAP irrigation premiums, as long as they are officially registered.
9 In the Adour case, no SAGE negotiations were initiated. However, the PGE is an equivalent framework, although the state is less involved in the process.
10 In some basins where a dam already exists, a double-bind contract was signed : farmers commit themselves, on an individual basis, to respecting the allowed quota. The water manager commits itself in return to guaranteeing that the water quota will be made available at least nine years out of ten to farmers, therefore reducing farmers' risk. This kind of contract is only possible when storage capacities allow to reduce short-term fluctuations of water resources (reduce inter-annual and intra-annual variations).
11 Dams are identified by the order in which they are planned to be built.
12 The limits between two sub-basins correspond to the points for which minimum low water flows were defined in SDAGE. The fourth sub-basin (Lees-Gabas) is not included in the simulations.
13 Although we have conducted other simulations in which the price can vary from one basin to another. We could also introduce multiple-tier prices.
14 Although in reality, there are technical constraints which do not allow perfect continuity.
15 This bias is the difference between the result of the aggregate model and the sum of the individual models.
16 We assume that the production function of a farm is given by h(q,x,z) = 0 where q is the vector of output quantities, x is the vector of variable input quantities and z is the vector of fixed factor quantity. If p is the input vector price, then the profit function can be approximated by a translog function :
(with given restrictions on parameters : see Sadoulet and de Janvry (1995)
17 As specified earlier, the political weight is translated into the model by an " access probability ". Therefore the sum of the political weights of all players is equal to 1.
.
Repartition of farms, agricultural area (in hectares) and irrigated area (in hectares) according to farm types and sub basins in the Adour Basin | ||||||||||
Sub basin | Farm types | traditional cattle farming | dairy farming | pig or poultry farming with cereals | small corn producers | mixed crop-livestock farming | corn producers with seeds or vegetable crops | corn producers with a complementary poultry farming | large corn producers | Together |
(1) Upstream sub basin | farm number | 75 | 32 | 16 | 357 | 38 | 16 | 0 | 63 | 597 |
agricultural area | 2273 | 1401 | 1195 | 6583 | 2451 | 1072 | 0 | 4022 | 18997 | |
irrigated area | 831 | 573 | 731 | 4400 | 970 | 744 | 0 | 2825 | 11074 | |
(2) Midstream sub basin | farm number | 37 | 10 | 28 | 165 | 35 | 39 | 21 | 0 | 335 |
agricultural area | 1199 | 709 | 2096 | 3181 | 2311 | 3296 | 1570 | 0 | 14363 | |
irrigated area | 396 | 350 | 1111 | 1943 | 1008 | 2241 | 1059 | 0 | 8108 | |
(3) Downstream sub basin | farm number | 34 | 18 | 24 | 240 | 30 | 8 | 46 | 0 | 400 |
agricultural area | 1043 | 869 | 1646 | 4463 | 2060 | 587 | 3145 | 0 | 13814 | |
irrigated area | 448 | 535 | 1052 | 2942 | 991 | 408 | 2153 | 0 | 8529 | |
(4) Lées Gabas | farm number | 105 | 41 | 47 | 216 | 60 | 16 | 44 | 0 | 529 |
agricultural area | 3379 | 1936 | 2723 | 4621 | 3709 | 1024 | 2942 | 0 | 20334 | |
irrigated area | 1315 | 744 | 1315 | 2577 | 1383 | 567 | 1591 | 0 | 9492 | |
Whole Adour Basin | farm number | 251 | 101 | 115 | 978 | 163 | 79 | 111 | 63 | 1861 |
agricultural area | 7894 | 4915 | 7660 | 18848 | 10531 | 5979 | 7657 | 4022 | 67508 | |
irrigated area | 2990 | 2202 | 4209 | 11862 | 4352 | 3960 | 4803 | 2825 | 37203 | |
Studied area | farm number | 146 | 60 | 68 | 762 | 103 | 63 | 67 | 63 | 1332 |
agricultural area | 4515 | 2979 | 4937 | 14227 | 6822 | 4955 | 4715 | 4022 | 47174 | |
irrigated area | 1675 | 1458 | 2894 | 9285 | 2969 | 3393 | 3212 | 2825 | 27711 | |
NB : the fourth sub basin (Lées-Gabas) is not included in the simulations
Parameters of the utility functions | |||||||
a0 | a1 | a2 | a3 | a4 | a5 | α | |
Upstream farmer | 3.605 | 0.421 | -0.105 | 0.506 | -0.045 | -0.190 | 0.9 |
Midstream farmer | 3.795 | 0.424 | -0.124 | 0.346 | -0.0161 | -0.194 | 0.75 |
Downstream farmer | 3.69 | 0.145 | 0.138 | 0.498 | -0.051 | -0.151 | 0.75 |
Landscape Env. | 0.2 | 0.08 | 0.72 | -0.5 | 0.7 | ||
River Env. | 0.8 | 0.02 | 0.18 | -0.5 | 0.7 | ||
Manager | 0.1 | 0.4 | 0.5 | 0.5 | 0.7 | ||
Taxpayer | 0.3 | 0.8 | 1 | ||||
It has to be noted that all utility functions are written U = Uα with α being a risk-aversion parameter.
Investment costs IC
IC = 0.25 (NDC)2 + 40with NDC new dam capacity in million m3
BARRETEAU O and Bousquet B (1999), "Jeux de rôles et validation de systèmes multi-agents " in Gleyzes MP and Marcenac P (Eds) Ingénierie des systèmes multi-agents. Actes des 7ème Journées Francophones d'Intelligence Artificielle et Systèmes Multi-Agents, Hermès Sciences Publications, pp. 67-80
CALDART C and Ashford N. (1998), "Negotiation as a means of developing and implementing environmental policy." Working paper, MIT, draft version, May 1998
FASSE N (1998), "L'eau entre Etat et usager dans le bassin de l'Adour : de la gestion réglementaire à la gestion concertée". DEA-Sciences de l'eau dans l'environnement continental. Montpellier. Septembre. 72p.
FASSE N and Morardet S (1999), "La mise en place d'une gestion négociée de l'eau en France : l'exemple de la gestion des étiages sur le bassin de l'Adour." Contributions to the 17th International Congress on Irrigation and Drainage "Water for agriculture in the next millennium", Granada, 1999, volume 1F, 29-46
GLEYSES G and Morardet S (1997), "Barrage de Gardères-Eslourenties. Evaluation économique de l'agriculture irriguée". Cemagref, Division Irrigation, Institution interdépartementale pour l'aménagement hydraulique du bassin de l'Adour, Compagnie d'Aménagement des Coteaux de Gascogne, Montpellier, 80 p.
GOODHUE R, Morardet S, Rio P and Thoyer S (1998), "Les formes institutionnelles de la gestion de l'eau en France et en Californie : droits de propriété, décentralisation et délégation." Contribution to the SFER Conference "Irrigation et gestion collective de l'eau en France et dans le Monde", Montpellier, 19-20 november 1998
KEENEY R, Raiffa H (1976) Decision with multiple objective: Preference and value tradeoffs. John Wiley.
RIO P, Morardet S and Thoyer S (1999), "Gestion de l'eau en France : l'efficacité des procédures négociées." Contribution to the Conference "Economie et Environnement", Strasbourg, 2-3 décembre 1999, 30 p.
PELLOW D (1999), Negotiation and confrontation: environmental policymaking through consensus. Society and Natural ressources, Vol 12, pp. 189-203
RAUSSER G and Simon L (1991), "A noncooperative model of collective decision making: A multilateral bargaining approach." Working Paper n°618, Department of Agricultural and Ressource Economics, University of California, Berkeley, 50 p.
RUBINSTEIN A (1982), "Perfect Equilibrium in a Bargaining Model." Econometrica, 50, pp. 97-109.
SADOULET E. and de Janvry A. (1995), Quantitative Development Policy Analysis. Baltimore, MA: Johns Hopkins University Press
Return to Contents of this issue
© Copyright Journal of Artificial Societies and Social Simulation, 2001